Sunday, October 27, 2019
John Kenneth Galbraith Biography
John Kenneth Galbraith Biography Archibald Galbraith, a Canadian schoolteacher, once climbed onto a platform atop aà steaming pile of manure to address a group of Liberal party voters before the coming Ontarioà elections. ââ¬Å"Before I begin,â⬠he said, ââ¬Å"I must apologize for speaking from the Tory platform.â⬠à Later on, his teenage son, John Kenneth, would congratulate him on the dig, to which heà [Archibald] would respond, ââ¬Å"It was good. But it didnââ¬â¢t change any votes.â⬠(Arthur Scheslinger,à 1984, p. 7) So, from an early age, John Kenneth Galbraith was between the world of politics andà pragmatism.à John Kenneth Galbraith was born in 1908. His fatherââ¬â¢s involvement in politics had aà profound impact on the young John Kenneth, politicizing him at an early age. He originallyà studied Agricultural Economics at the Ontario Agricultural College, but would eventually sayà that he took his first ââ¬Å"realâ⬠economics course at UC Berkeley, and that the economics instructionà in Canada was ââ¬Å"very poorâ⬠(Dunn, 2002, p. 350). As a graduate student at UC Berkeley, heà continued his study of agricultural economics and worked as a research assistant for a ââ¬Å"very zanyà old man by the name of Edwin Voorhiesâ⬠(Kreisler, 1986). He stated that it was his study ofà agricultural economics that left him with a strong feeling that ââ¬Å"social science should be tested byà its usefulness,â⬠an idea inspired by Veblenââ¬â¢s dichotomy between exoteric knowledge (knowledgeà that is valuable and applicable) and esoteric knowledge (knowledge tha t has no practicalà application, but because of that, is considered more ââ¬Å"prestigiousâ⬠). Galbraith believed that socialà sciences should be exoteric, not esoteric. In his book Economics and The Public Purpose,à Galbraith develops this idea further, saying, ââ¬Å"The ultimate test of a set of economic ideas isà whether it illuminates the anxietes of the timeâ⬠(Galbraith, 1973, p.198). In the 1930ââ¬â¢s, while Galbraith was studying to receive his Ph. D, it was clear thatà economic theory was not addressing the anxietes of the time. Economists were struggling toà explain how free markets had led the United States to economic ruin. One in four Americansà were jobless. Production had all but ground to a halt. Obviously, there were egregious errors inà the accepted dogma, which stated that free markets left to their own devices would bring aboutà efficiency and employment. Galbraith said that his method of coming to an understanding was toà ââ¬Å"for yearsâ⬠¦start with [Alfred] Marshall, see the world as it is, and make the requisiteà modificationsâ⬠(Dunn, 2002, p. 351). Upon graduating, Galbraith traveled to Washington D.C.à and took a position assisting with the implementation of the Agricultural Adjustment Act, beforeà taking a position as a tutor at Harvard. At Harvard, he made speeches supporting the reelection of Roosevelt, cement ing his initial ties with the Democratic party. Not long after, he was offeredà a fellowship at Cambridge, where the discussions centered around Keynes, who had just published his General Theory of Employment, Money, and Interest (Dunn, 2002, pp. 350-355).à Galbraith returned from England to his tutor position at Harvard a confirmed Keynesian. He spent a few more years tutoring at Harvard (where he met John F. Kennedy) and then took aà job as resident economist for the American Farm Bureau Federation in Washington. Galbraithââ¬â¢sà observation of the farm industry solidified his belief in the power of government to moveà industries forward. In 1930, farm households accounted for a quarter of the population, whereasà today they account for only 1% of the population and yet on the whole, they now produce moreà than they did in 1930. This is due to strong government support of the farming industry. Thatà national planning could ââ¬Å"transform a weak, disorganized, and poverty prone sector of theà economy into Americaââ¬â¢s most spectacular productive successâ⬠¦preserved his political concernsâ⬠à (Arthur Schlesinger, 1984, p. 8). Galbraith became head of the Office of Price Administration inà 1941 during World War II, and at the same time began his long career as a ghostwriter, penningà spe eches for Samuel Rosenman and Robert Sherwood (Arthur Schlesinger, 1984, p. 8). Galbraith then became editor of Fortune magazine, where he worked directly for Harryà Luce, founder of Time Inc., whom he called ââ¬Å"one of the most ruthless editors I have ever known,à or anyone has ever knownâ⬠(Kreisler, 1986). Galbraith has credited Luce with dramaticallyà improving his writing via ruthless editing. Galbraith credited Fortune with giving him aà ââ¬Å"marvelous introduction to the corporate mind,â⬠because the focus of the magazine at the timeà was ââ¬Å"the anatomy of the big corporationsâ⬠(Dunn, 2002, p. 353). The decision making processesà of major corporations would be a recurring phenomenon that he would write about in many ofà his publications. Galbraith returned to Academia in 1948, having spent five years as editor of Fortune. Heà was nominated to a position teaching economics at Harvard. However, members of Harvardââ¬â¢sà board of overseers regarded him as a ââ¬Å"dangerous Keynesian,â⬠and as a result, ââ¬Å"took the step,à almost unprecedented in modern times, of blocking the appointmentâ⬠(Dunn, 2002, p. 353). However, Galbraith had many political allies, and among them was Harvardââ¬â¢s president, Jamesà B. Conant. Conant was such a fan of Galbraith that he threatened to resign unless the board ofà overseers backed down. Eventually they did, and Galbraith became a tenured professor atà Harvard. It was then that he began work on his first major bestseller, American Capitalism: Theà Concept of Countervailing Power. Galbraith begins his discussion of capitalism in America by pointing out the followingà conundrum: Mainstream economic theory asserts that in the case of monopoly, prices will rise,à business will screw consumers, fail to innovate, and as a result, the economy will be in badà shape. He then notes the work of Joan Robinson in developing the idea of monopolistic andà oligopolistic competition, noting that oligopolistic industries behave in the same way asà monopolies would, and through informal agreements can have the exact same effect. Then, usingà the actual data collected by the American government, he shows that the majority of industriesà are in fact oligopolistic. But he goes even further than that, saying that almost all industries willà eventually become oligopolistic for the following reasons: At the birth of an industry,à competetion is necessary and possible, as no firms have clear and significant advantages yet. Butà over time, it will become increasingl y difficult to enter the industry because of the barriers toà entry created by high capital requirements and increasing returns to scale. At the same time thatà increasing returns to scale start to set in (as they inevitably do), existing firms will also gain theà advantage of experience and prior organization. The convergence of these factors leads, in mostà cases, to an industry with a few power players and a larger but still relatively small number ofà hangers-on, who exist by filling niches that arenââ¬â¢t worth the time of the large firms. Galbraith poses a question in American Capitalism, and before getting to that question, ità is important to get a sense of the context in which he asks it. After World War II, America wasà experiencing incredible prosperity. But underlying this prosperity was the fear of depression. Theà Great Depression was still fresh in the collective consciousness, and the average manââ¬â¢s faith thatà capitalism would bring about efficiency and full employment was shaken. And yet, as the yearsà after the war progressed, things were stable and employment was plentiful. It is also important toà note that the era of non-depression Keynesianism was beginning, and much to the chagrin of theà business community, government was becoming a much more participatory force in markets. The business community was reacting violently against this expansion of government, claimingà that it was a complete disaster, wasteful to the very extreme and bound to cripple growth. Theà state of the American economy in the 1950ââ¬â¢s then was that of big government, near-ubiquitousà monopoly or oligopoly, and an underlying fear of depression. Yet, by almost any measure, theà economy was a success. The problem, according to Galbraith, was that, ââ¬Å"in principle, the economy pleased noà one; in practice it satisfied most. Social inefficiency [government spending], unrationalizedà power [monopoly and oligopoly], intrusive government [regulation], and depression were allà matters for deep concern. But neither liberal nor conservatives, neither the rich nor all but theà very poor, found the consequences intolerableâ⬠(Galbraith, 1954, p. 85). What fascinatedà Galbraith was how an economy which was so flawed in theory could work so well in practice. The question he asked was: Why are things soâ⬠¦wellâ⬠¦good? Thus, he states that his aim inà American Capitalism is to ââ¬Å"examine in turn the circumstances that have kept social inefficiency,à private power, government intervention, and unemployment from ruining us in the recentà presentâ⬠(Galbraith, 1954, p. 85). The first answer that he gives is that oligopoly is much more conducive to techonologicalà innovation than classical competetion. ââ¬Å"There is no more pleasant fiction than that technicalà change is the product of the matchless ingenuity of the small man forced by competition toà employ his wits to better his neighbor. Unhappily, it is a fiction,â⬠he says. ââ¬Å"Technicalà development has long since become the preserve of the scientist and engineerâ⬠(Galbraith, 1954,à p.86). His argument is that due to the costliness of development, it can only be undertaken by aà firm with considerable resources. In highly competitive industries, no one firm has considerableà resources. Moreover, because innovations can easily be imitated, it is not economical for a smallà competitive firm to bear the research and development costs for an entire industry. Galbraith then turns his keen eye to the idea of inefficiency. He deals with this issue byà asserting that Americaââ¬â¢s relative opulence shields us and is moreover a cause of suchà inefficiency. At the time that the classical economists were writing, an opulent economy had yetà to be observed. For Malthus and Ricardo, ââ¬Å"inefficiency was, indeed, an evil thing. It deniedà bread to the hungry and clothing to the nakedâ⬠(Galbraith, 1954, p.102). The true power ofà Galbraithââ¬â¢s insight is his ability to point out the obvious. He criticizes his fellow economists forà bringing the mentality of the nineteenth century, with all its poverty and degradation, to theà opulent twentieth century. Galbraith finds this error both amusing and absurd, saying, ââ¬Å"He [theà mainstream economist] worries far too much about partially monopolized pricesâ⬠¦for tobacco, liquor, automobiles, and soap, in a land which is already suffering from nicotine poisoning and à alcoholism, which is nutritionally gorged with sugar, which is filling its hospitals and cemeteriesà with those who have been maimed or murdered on its highways, and which is dangerouslyà neurotic about body odorsâ⬠(Galbraith, 1954, p.102). His point is that these inefficiencies are inà fact a sign of the wealth of America. They are the symptom of a wealthy economy, and thus weà ought not to worry so much about them. He also discredits the idea of intrusive government,à noting that, ââ¬Å"alarm over pending action by government on economic matters, which frequentlyà reaches almost pathological proportions when the decision is pending, almost invariablyà evaporates completely once the action is taken. One of the profound sources of Americanà strength has been the margin of error provided by our well-beingâ⬠(Galbraith, 1954, p.106). But the most significant reason that monopoly has failed to capsize the Americanà economy, according to Galbraith is the exercise of what he calls countervailing power. Theà assumption always made by economists, when they would consider the case of markets, was thatà the check on an individual firmââ¬â¢s power wold come from the supply side of the industry. Galbraith disagrees. He admits that the existence of monopoly power in a competitive marketà does in fact encourage the entry of more producers to appropriate some of that power forà themselves. ââ¬Å"In other words,â⬠he says. ââ¬Å"Competition was regarded [and is] a self-generatingà regulatory forceâ⬠(Galbraith, 1954, p. 112). But in a market that is not competitive, the incentive for some economic agent toà approptiate that power still exists. But it need not come from the supply side. That power is, inà practice, usually appropriated by strong buyers or coalitions of buyers, who can sometimes takeà even more than their share. Because of the tendency of power to be organized in response toà existing power, ââ¬Å"countervailing power is also a self-generating forceâ⬠(Galbraith, 1954, p. 113). According to Galbraith, it is the large retailers who, by way of their absolute power overà manufacturers, bargain for the consumer and protect the consumer from the high monopolyà prices that would otherwise result. Likewise, the considerable market power of large firms isà checked by trade unions for a simple reason, there is something to be bargained for Galbraithà notes that trade unions are most powerful in the least competitive industries. This is because theà surplus that a company derives from monopoly power acts as an incentive to unions. In the veryà competitive industries, producers and workers are operating at bare minimum profit and theà incentives to organization insignificant. These are the basic ideas laid out in American Capitalism. The book in many ways laysà the framework and tone for the books he would publish in the sixties and seventies. But whileà American Capitalism was Galbraithââ¬â¢s first major bestseller, it was The Affluent Society thatà skyrocketed him to fame. The Affluent Society builds on many of the concepts introduced in hisà first book, but with several key differences. Though Galbraith could not suppress his urge toà social commentary, The Affluent Society is a much more prescriptive book, growing out of hisà chapter on technical development in American Capitalism. To his original analysis he adds aà significantly moral component. The Affluent Society concerns itself with the policies that oughtà to be undertaken once the basic needs of the people have been met. Galbraithââ¬â¢s main argument isà that our ratio of private good (cars, televisions, automobiles) to public goods (schools, roads) isà inequitable an d ridiculous. The premise of his argument is that once our basic desires such asà food, clothing, and shelter have been satisfied, large corporations employ advertising to concoctà new demand for products. The traditional economic and utilitarian argument for goods quaà goods falls on its face if consumer demand is not sovereign. What is really necessary is the useà of societyââ¬â¢s productive resources in the public realm in juxtaposition with growth in the privateà realm. He calls this idea ââ¬Å"social balance,â⬠saying, ââ¬Å"the problem of social balance is ubiquitous,à and frequently it is obtrusive. As noted, an increase in the consumption of automobiles requires aà facilitating supply of streets, highways, traffic control, and parking spacesâ⬠(Galbraith, 1958, p.à 193). He also confronts the existence of poverty in an affluent society as being the result ofà outdated nineteenth century attitudes. ââ¬Å"A poor society,â⬠he says, ââ¬Å "had to enforce the rule thatà someone who did not work could not eat. An affluent society has no similar excuse for suchà rigorâ⬠(Galbraith, 1958, p. 251). But he admits that, ââ¬Å"nothing requires such a society to beà compassionate. But it no longer has a high philosophical justification for its callousnessâ⬠à (Galbraith, 1958, p. 251). In the 50ââ¬â¢s, America was in the midst of the cold war and attempts at engineering a betterà society were very suspect. Galbraith throughout The Affluent Society understands the inherentà and ideological opposition to big government and social policy, but he is adamant in stating,à ââ¬Å"that citiesââ¬â¢ residents should have a nontoxic supply of air suggests no revolutionary dalliance with socialismâ⬠(Galbraith, 1958, p. 191). In fact, Galbraith eventually finds socialism and central planning to be in many waysà similar to the kind of capitalism that developed in America in the latter half of the 20th century. 9 In The New Industral State, Galbraith focuses his effort on understanding what he calls theà ââ¬Å"technostructure.â⬠In an era when the division of intellectual labor is so overwhelming, theà management or even management team of a powerful corporation doesnââ¬â¢t actually make most ofà the decisions. The decisions are instead made collectively by teams of experts. Galbraith coinsà the term technostructure as, ââ¬Å"embracing all who bring specialized knowledge, talent orà experience to group decision-making. This,â⬠he says, ââ¬Å"not the management, is the guidingà intelligence, the brain, of the enterpriseâ⬠(Galbraith, 1967, p.71). Many of Galbraithââ¬â¢s ideas resonate to this day. Unfortunately, most do not. It would beà tempting to end this essay optimistically, expounding poetically on the way Galbraithââ¬â¢s ideasà continue to influence national policy. In reality, although he was a well-respected and powerfulà man, many of his ideas continue to be ignored by mainstream economists and politicians. Rarelyà does one hear a contemporary economist talk about countervailing power, or reference theà ââ¬Å"technostructure.â⬠While as a society we owe much to Galbraith and his ideas, the discipline ofà economics has for all intents and purposes laid his practical ideas by the wayside. But whether orà not his continued influence on economics is felt by the mainstream, his contribution to theà discipline remains poignant and accessible for those who choose to seek it out on their own. Galbraithââ¬â¢s main contribution to economic thought was his tackling of the problem ofà power. He was convinced that the most glaring, most significant, and most ignored problem inà the field of economics was the effect of power on economic activity. Understanding whyà Galbraith was so affixed by this idea of power is actually quite simple; he was surrounded by it. Through his political work, Galbraith knew not only Kennedy, but several other presidents andà all the most powerful officials in the democratic party. Through his work at Fortune he becameà acquainted with the heads of the largest and most powerful corporations in the world. He saw,à 10 clearly, the extent to which the decisions of these men (and the technostructures supportingà them) affected the direction and performance of the economy of the whole. Given that he was anà astute man, for him to ignore the influence of power on economies, in order to advance a seriesà of aesthetically pleasing models and equations, would have been not only unthinkable butà dishonest. Galbraith wanted badly to be useful, to ââ¬Å"change votes,â⬠as his father would have said. To him, sitting in a room concocting theories did not qualify as usefulness. He longed to be inà the thick of policy-making. Later in life, he wanted badly to avoid what he called ââ¬Å"Belmont Syndromeâ⬠1 Thus, his struggle to be relevant was not only ideological but moral. John Kenneth Galbraith died peacefully at home in 2006. He left behind not only anà extensive body of economic work, but two novels. His first novel, The Triumph, written in 1969,à was about U.S. foreign policy disasters in Latin America. His second novel, A Tenuredà Professor, written in 1990, was about an eccentric Harvard professor, and lampooned the eliteà institution. He lived ninety-seven years, almost all of them (excepting the first few) wereà preoccupied with upending the ââ¬Å"conventional wisdom.â⬠He remains one of the most famous andà controversial economists of the twentieth century, and a fine novelist.
Subscribe to:
Post Comments (Atom)
No comments:
Post a Comment
Note: Only a member of this blog may post a comment.